Back to Vocabulary

Green Land Value Tax

Area: Design, planning and building

As a response to the regressiveness of housing taxation and the subsidisation model of housing renovation, (Muellbauer, 2018) has introduced the idea of a Green Land Value Tax (GLVT). The GLVT is composed of two elements, one based on built-up surface and another one on unoccupied land. Energy-efficient buildings would pay the same tax as unoccupied land while energy-inefficient ones would pay a proportional increase by energy use. Such tax would create incentives to retrofit and improve the financial viability of increasing densities as the tax burden on built-up surface could be shared by different households in multiple occupation buildings but concentrated in one in the case of single-family dwellings.

In this regard, the study of policies such as mortgage interest deduction has pointed out how

the lack of adequate taxation leads to the overconsumption of owner-occupied housing and increases in house prices (Fatica & Prammer, 2018) (Poterba, 1984). On the one hand, targeting grants to households could incentivise retrofit among low-income homeowners for whom the impact of increased costs could pose affordability problems. On the other hand, increased taxation of energy-inefficient homes could help redistribute housing wealth toward younger homeowners in the most energy-efficient proportions of the stock and incentivise retrofit through increasing housing costs for house- wealthy households. However, the political feasibility of these drastic policy changes remains questionable.

Although there is no land value taxation in the Netherlands, the Dutch case remains particularly apposite to test green taxation proposals through imputed rent as done in Fernandez et. al (2024). The Netherlands lacks tax neutrality across tenures and imposes regressive taxes on energy consumption. These renovation incentivising policies result from a consumption interpretation of housing renovation as a one-off expense, not as an investment resulting in the appreciation of a financial asset (Copiello & Donati, 2021). Albeit under-taxing it according to the literature presented before, Dutch fiscal policy treats owner-occupied housing as an asset (Haffner, 2003). Aligning incentives for renovation with the asset interpretation of housing present in fiscal policy opens up paths for a set of green tax tools (Fernandez et. al, 2024).

This concept is an excerpt from the article Fernández, A., Haffner, M. & Elsinga, M. Subsidies or green taxes? Evaluating the distributional effects of housing renovation policies among Dutch households. J Hous and the Built Environ (2024). https://doi.org/10.1007/s10901-024-10118-5

References

Copiello, S., & Donati, E. (2021). Is investing in energy efficiency worth it? Evidence for substantial price premiums but limited profitability in the housing sector. Energy and Buildings, 251, 111371. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.enbuild.2021.111371

Fatica, S., & Prammer, D. (2018). Housing and the Tax System: How Large Are the Distortions in the Euro Area?*. Fiscal Studies, 39(2), 299–342. https://doi.org/10.1111/1475-5890.12159

Haffner, M. (2003). Tenure Neutrality, a Financial-Economic Interpretation. Housing Theory and Society, 20, 72–85. https://doi.org/10.1080/14036090310001903

Muellbauer, J. (2018). Housing, debt and the economy: A tale of two countries. National Institute Economic Review, 245, R20–R33. https://doi.org/10.1177/002795011824500112

Poterba, J. M. (1984). Tax Subsidies to Owner-Occupied Housing: An Asset-Market Approach. Source: The Quarterly Journal of Economics, 99(4), 729–752.

Created on 14-10-2024 | Update on 16-10-2024

Related definitions

No entries

Related cases

No entries

Related publications

No entries

Relational graph

icon case study Case Study
icon case study Concept
icon case study Publication
icon case study Blogposts